Skip to content
SuperMoney logo
SuperMoney logo

Neutrality of Money: Explained, Examples, and Implications

Last updated 03/19/2024 by

Silas Bamigbola

Edited by

Fact checked by

Summary:
The neutrality of money, also known as neutral money, is an economic theory that suggests changes in the money supply primarily impact nominal variables, such as prices and wages, rather than real variables like the structure and output of the economy. While some economists believe that the theory holds in the long run, others argue that it may have short-term effects. In this article, we’ll delve deeper into the neutrality of money, its history, criticism, and its impact on economic equilibrium.

Understanding the neutrality of money

The concept of the neutrality of money is rooted in the idea that money is essentially a neutral factor with no substantial impact on economic equilibrium. Even when the money supply increases, it’s thought to have little to no effect on the fundamental nature of the economy. Instead, the theory suggests that all markets for goods continuously clear, with relative prices adjusting flexibly toward equilibrium. Changes in the money supply do not seem to alter the underlying conditions in the economy.
This means that the introduction of new money does not create or destroy machines, nor does it introduce new trading partners or affect existing knowledge and skills. As a result, aggregate supply, which represents the total amount of goods and services that an economy can produce, should remain relatively constant.
However, it’s important to note that not all economists subscribe to this way of thinking. Many believe that the neutrality of money theory primarily applies over the long term. In fact, the assumption of long-run money neutrality underpins most macroeconomic theories, providing mathematical economists with a stable set of predictive parameters.
An example of the neutrality of money can be observed when a macroeconomist studies the monetary policy of a central bank, such as the Federal Reserve (Fed). In this context, changes in the money supply are not expected to alter future capital equipment, employment levels, or real wealth in the long-run equilibrium. According to the theory, these factors should remain constant.

Neutrality of money history

The roots of money neutrality can be traced back to the Cambridge tradition in economics that existed between 1750 and 1870. Early versions of this theory posited that changes in the level of money supply could not impact output or employment, not even in the short run. This was based on the presumption that the aggregate supply curve is vertical, meaning changes in the price level do not significantly affect aggregate output.
However, not all classical economists accepted this notion. Some believed that short-term factors, like price stickiness or depressed business confidence, could lead to non-neutrality, where changes in the money supply could affect the economy’s output and employment levels.
The term “neutrality of money” was first introduced by Austrian economist Friedrich A. Hayek in 1931. Initially, Hayek defined it as a market rate of interest at which poorly allocated business investments, according to Austrian business cycle theory, did not occur and did not produce business cycles. This concept later evolved, and neoclassical and neo-Keynesian economists adopted the term, giving it the current meaning it holds in economic theory.

Neutrality of money vs. superneutrality of money

A stronger version of the neutrality of money theory is known as the superneutrality of money. This theory posits that changes in the rate of money supply growth do not have any impact on economic output, except for real money balances. Superneutrality assumes that money growth has no effect on real variables, except for real money balances, and disregards short-run frictions. It is particularly relevant to an economy accustomed to a constant money growth rate.

Criticism of the neutrality of money

Despite its widespread acceptance in economic theory, the neutrality of money has not been without criticism. Several notable economists, including John Maynard Keynes, Ludwig von Mises, and Paul Davidson, have rejected the concept both in the short and long run. The post-Keynesian school and the Austrian school of economics are among those that dismiss the theory.
Critics argue that variations in the money supply can affect relative prices over long periods. According to this view, as the money supply increases, the value of money decreases. Over time, as the increased supply of money circulates throughout the economy, the prices of goods and services will rise to reach an equilibrium point by offsetting the increase in the money supply.
Furthermore, critics contend that an increase in the money supply can impact consumption and production. As the supply of money increases, it drives up prices, which, in turn, affects how individuals and businesses interact with the economy.

Is money truly neutral?

The debate surrounding the neutrality of money continues, with economists on both sides of the argument presenting compelling cases. While some believe that changes in the money supply have minimal long-term effects on the real economy, others argue that it can indeed impact various aspects of economic life.
In practice, the neutrality of money is a concept that provides a framework for understanding the relationship between monetary policy and the broader economy. Its implications can influence the decisions made by central banks, governments, and policymakers when managing the money supply and setting interest rates.

Theoretical and practical implications

The neutrality of money theory has both theoretical and practical implications for economists, policymakers, and financial institutions. Let’s explore these in more detail.

Theoretical implications

In the realm of economic theory, the concept of money neutrality plays a vital role in shaping how we understand and model the behavior of an economy. Economists often use the neutrality of money as a fundamental assumption when developing macroeconomic models. This assumption simplifies the analysis and allows for a more manageable framework.
For example, when constructing models to predict the effects of changes in monetary policy, economists typically assume that in the long run, the neutrality of money holds. This simplification enables them to make more accurate predictions about the impacts of various policy changes on nominal variables, such as inflation and interest rates.

Practical implications

In practice, the neutrality of money has significant implications for monetary policy and central banks. Central banks are responsible for managing the money supply and interest rates to achieve their policy objectives, such as controlling inflation and stabilizing the economy.
If the neutrality of money holds true, it implies that changes in the money supply, brought about by central bank actions like open market operations or interest rate adjustments, should primarily affect nominal variables like prices and wages. Real economic variables, such as the overall level of output or employment, should remain relatively unaffected in the long run.
This has practical implications for central banks when they are making decisions about monetary policy. For example, if they want to combat inflation, they may raise interest rates to reduce the money supply growth, assuming that these actions will primarily impact prices and wages without causing significant disruptions to the real economy.
However, the extent to which the neutrality of money holds in the real world is still a matter of debate. Some critics argue that in the short and long run, changes in the money supply can indeed influence real economic variables. This debate adds complexity to the decision-making process of central banks, as they must consider the potential real-world effects of their actions.

Monetary policy and the neutrality of money

A crucial aspect of the neutrality of money theory is its relationship with monetary policy. Central banks around the world use monetary policy tools
to control the money supply, influence interest rates, and achieve specific economic goals. Let’s explore how this theory relates to monetary policy.

Monetary policy tools

Central banks employ various tools to conduct monetary policy. These tools include open market operations, discount rates, and reserve requirements. The central idea behind these actions is to influence the money supply, which, according to the neutrality of money theory, should primarily impact nominal variables.
For example, if a central bank wants to stimulate economic growth, it may decrease interest rates and engage in open market operations to increase the money supply. According to the theory, this should lead to lower interest rates, increased spending, and potentially higher prices.

Real-world considerations

While the neutrality of money is a useful theoretical concept, it’s essential to recognize that the real world is often more complex. Economic conditions, market expectations, and various other factors can influence the actual outcomes of monetary policy.

Conclusion

The neutrality of money is a fundamental concept in economics that has been the subject of debate and discussion for centuries. While it suggests that changes in the money supply primarily affect nominal variables rather than real variables, its true applicability and significance remain a matter of contention among economists. The theory has provided valuable insights into the world of monetary policy and macroeconomics, shaping the way we understand and manage money in our modern economies.

Frequently asked questions

Is the neutrality of money a universally accepted theory?

The neutrality of money theory is widely accepted in economic circles, but not without its share of critics. While some economists argue that it holds true in the long run, others believe it may have short-term effects on the economy. The theory’s applicability remains a subject of debate.

How does the neutrality of money affect monetary policy?

The concept of the neutrality of money has significant implications for monetary policy and central banks. It suggests that changes in the money supply primarily impact nominal variables, like prices and wages, rather than real economic variables. Understanding this theory is crucial for central banks when making decisions about managing the money supply and setting interest rates.

What is the difference between the neutrality of money and the superneutrality of money?

The superneutrality of money is a more extreme version of the neutrality of money theory. It posits that changes in the rate of money supply growth do not affect any real economic variables except for real money balances. Understanding the distinctions between these two concepts is essential for a deeper grasp of monetary theory.

What criticisms exist regarding the neutrality of money theory?

While the neutrality of money is widely accepted, it has faced criticism from notable economists, including John Maynard Keynes, Ludwig von Mises, and Paul Davidson. Critics argue that variations in the money supply can affect relative prices over extended periods, impacting consumption and production. This section delves into the criticisms surrounding the theory.

How does the neutrality of money theory impact economic modeling?

Economists often use the neutrality of money as a fundamental assumption when constructing economic models. This simplification allows for more accurate predictions about the effects of changes in monetary policy on nominal variables, such as inflation and interest rates. Understanding its role in economic modeling provides insights into the analytical tools used in economic research and policy development.

Key takeaways

  • The neutrality of money theory suggests that changes in the money supply primarily affect nominal variables like prices and wages.
  • While some economists believe it holds in the long run, others argue that it may have short-term effects.
  • Superneutrality of money is a stronger version of this theory, suggesting that money supply growth has no impact on economic output.
  • Critics argue that variations in the money supply can affect relative prices and impact consumption and production.

Share this post:

You might also like